So the task force on Payment Reform issued a report declaring (without actually bother to prove) that our fee-for-service payment system, by which we reimburse physicians per visit or per procedure, was driving up costs by giving them an incentive to overtreat patients. This task force recommended we instead move to a system of “global capitation” whereby we pay physicians and hospitals a fixed amount for treating a patient for a whole year, removing this incentive. This report – which is 100% wrong in its assumption that fee-for-service is a significant cause of rising health care costs – is the basis for the expected next round of health reform.
Next came the two very good studies looking at the causes of rising costs in Massachusetts: one by the Division of Health Care Finance and Policy, the other by the Attorney General’s office. They both came to the same conclusion: our costs were not rising because doctors or hospitals were overtreating patients, or because the quantity of care was rising from year to year; our costs were going up because the price of providing the same exact procedure, or the same exact visit, were going up from year to year. In fact, the AG’s report found that providers being paid on a per-patient basis were actually among the most expensive in the state; this finding was accompanied by one of the most politically tactful comments you will ever encounter, reflecting that the state’s proposals for global payment reform have no evidence in current reality.
When you go to a doctor, you expect evidence-based medicine, but don’t hold your breath for evidence-based health policy. The rush is now on to implement “Accountable Care Organizations,” which will prevent our health providers from overtreating patients – a problem that all of the state’s own research, in addition to virtually all national research and all international research tells us is not the actual problem. A very balanced 2009 review of the evidence on Accountable Care Organizations by the Urban Institute concludes that there is little evidence they will have a large impact on costs, but the jury is still out and more experiments will be necessary to know more.
What we do know is that the version of ACOs being pushed in Massachusetts essentially revives two policies of the managed care revolution in the 1990s that were largely abandoned after massive patient and provider push-back: capitation and limited networks.
“Capitation” is the practice of paying providers a fixed amount to care for a patient over the course of the year: that amount will not go up or down, no matter how healthy or sick the patient becomes. What this means is that instead of insurance companies bearing the risk for a patient, providers bear the risk. If a patient is healthier than expected and uses little care, the provider will make money off of that patient; if the patient is sicker than expected or suffers an unexpected accident, the provider will lose money. The obvious problem is that, just as insurance companies have an incentive to avoid the sick when they bear the risk for patients, moving to a capitation system means that providers now have an incentive to avoid the sick or to undertreat them. This led to a backlash when managed care companies first introduced capitation in the 1990s, and it is now an uncommon practice in Massachusetts.
Limited networks were also a hallmark of early managed care, forcing patients to receive care only from a limited number of hospitals and doctors. While this sounds like a fine way to reduce costs, it is fine only until you change jobs and have to leave the physicians you know and trust because they are out of network. Limited networks are an intentional barrier to access – they do not exist in countries with universal health care (that, is, all of the rest of them in the developed world) – and they undermine continuity of care, which is considered incredibly important for quality of care in the medical world. Limited networks have also become unusual in Massachusetts, but they would be imposed on virtually everyone if the proposal for accountable care organizations were implemented.
The Boston Globe has covered payment reform extensively and has done, I think it’s fair to say, a horrible job. They have accurately covered the politics of payment reform, but have not looked at the evidence – for and against – of whether it will actually work to control costs. Health care costs are the top economic issue for virtually all small businesses, and for most households in the state. Residents deserve news that actually attempts to sort legitimate cost control from snake oil, but they’re not getting it. The march for payment reform seems to have taken on a life of its own, despite the state’s own diligent work establishing that fee-for-service is not driving up costs. The bill will be an opportunity for public advocacy by those who are affected by rising health care costs – let’s hope it’s not a wasted opportunity.
Benjamin Day is the Executive Director of Mass-Care: The Massachusetts Campaign for Single Payer Health Care, and serves as the statewide coordinator for Massachusetts Physicians for a National Health Program.
charley-on-the-mta says
So … capitation wasn’t the answer. ACO’s aren’t the answer.
<
p>Uh … what’s the answer? You say single-payer — how much does single-payer pay if single-payer could pay?
gp2b3a says
Medicare for all is what most progressives want. As you know, Medicare pays what they feel is the cost of a procedure. Your doctor submits a bill for 100$ and medicare typically pays about 60$. Doctors caught on to this by hiring savvy billing managers and that 100$ procedure now they bill 160$ for it to get their 100$ they originally wanted. Medicare payments will bankrupt the system. Here are some ideas that could work:
<
p>1. Incent patients to manage their own care and watch cost come down:
A. Offer choice to patietns for electives: MRI at the Brigham costs them 100$ out of pocket, same MRI at South Shore Hospital we pay the patient 100$ ( savings would be found by getting cheaper MRI at SSH vs Brigham)
<
p>When the Brigham sees that their MRI machine usage is down they will scratch their heads and figure out they charge too much and like magic their cost will come down.
<
p>2. Open access to health care practioners
<
p>A. By limiting the number of people patients can access for their healthcare you artifically drive up cost. AMA limitis the number of new applicants to medcial school each year. Add more seats and medical schools and more doctors will be avaialble to treat patients. More doctors will mean some will work for less money.
<
p>Allow allied health professionals to take larger roles in treating patients. I dont need a MD to manage my high blood pressure. A NP or RN could easily take this job and free up the MD to spend more time with more serious patients. A NP or RN would cost me less per visit. CVS has rolled out their Minute Clinics in New England and it is a great concept. Fast quality care that is easy to find and park. Why deal with Boston traffic, hospitals have so many serious disease in the hallways that infection rates at hospitals are dangerous. Send less serious patients to CVS or other like it. But, in the infinite wisdon of Beacon Hill succombing to Partners Helathcare and the rest of the “medical cartel” here in Boston they have limited what CVS can offer patients. When you limit patient choice you increase cost. CVS can treat blood pressure, diabetes and other chnronic illness in VT CT NH ME but not in Mass. Why is Mass so special? CVS can only treat sore throat, small scrapes adn scratches etc etc in Mass, what a shame. Provide more accesspoints for care, make it cheaper, and you will see outocmes improve and cost come down
<
p>these are two easy simple changes that would help, i am sure others have ideas as well, but the cartel and the govt dont want this, they want to control you and in the end tight control cost more